تاریخ انتشار:۱۰ خرداد ۱۳۹۵در ۱۲:۴۶ ب.ظ کد خبر:1190 تعداد بازديد: 847 بازدید

GIOVANNI DOSI

GIOVANNI DOSI

Born on August 25, 1953 in Fiorenzuola d’Arda (Piacenza), Italy.

 

 

 

Giovanni Dosi is Professor of Economics and Director of the Institute of Economics at the Scuola Superiore Sant’Anna in Pisa; Co-Director of the task forces “Industrial Policy” and “Intellectual Property Rights”, IPD – Initiative for Policy Dialogue at Columbia University; Continental European Editor of Industrial and Corporate Change. Included in “ISI Highly Cited Researchers”.

His major research areas – where he is author and editor of several works – include economics of innovation and technological change, industrial organization and industrial dynamics, theory of the firm and corporate governance, evolutionary theory, economic growth and development.

A selection of his works has been published in two volumes: Innovation,Organization and Economic Dynamics. Selected Essays, Cheltenham, Edward Elgar, 2000; and Economic Organization,Industrial Dynamics and Development: Selected Essays, Cheltenham, Edward Elgar, 2012.

Giovanni Dosi’s economic analysis is characterized by the contemporaneous attempt to (i) identify empirical regularities and (ii) provide micro-foundations consistent with such regularities. As such, his work is a mix of statistical investigations and theoretical efforts.

EDUCATION

July 1983                                                D. Phil., Economics, University of Sussex (Supervisor T. Barna), with a dissertation on Technical Change and Industrial Transformation. The Theory and an Application to the Semiconductor Industry

۱۹۷۷-۷۸                                   Specialization at ISTAO, Ancona, Italy

February 1976                                       “Laurea”, Faculty of Philosophy with a thesis on Keynes’ General Theory: Income Distribution and Economic Activity.

Technical change

The role of technological progress as an explanation of contemporary economic growth has led Dosi to carefully analyze the nature of technology. In particular, he has suggested an interpretation of technical change resting on the concepts of technological paradigm and technology trajectory.

In analogy with Thomas Kuhn’s definition of a scientific paradigm, Dosi has defined a technological paradigm as the general outlook on the productive problems faced by firms. As such, a technological paradigm is composed by some sort of model of the technology at stake (e.g. the model of a microprocessor) and by the specific technological problems posed by such model (e.g. increasing computational capacity, reducing dimensions, etc.). Therefore, technology is identified as a problem-solving activity in which the problems to be solved are selected by the paradigm itself. In this sense, a technological paradigm entails strong prescriptions on the direction of technological change, that is the direction toward which future technical improvements will converge. Such gradual improvements along the specific lines prescribed by the paradigm are what constitute technological trajectories and progress.

Such interpretation of technological change brings Dosi to identify a limited influence of market signals on the direction of technological change. More precisely, in his view relative prices might affect the direction of technological change only within the boundaries defined by the nature of the technological paradigm. Such idea can be better understood by analyzing the effect of market signals in their two possible directions: moving “downstream” (i.e. from the technology to the sale of goods) and “upstream” (i.e. from the market environment to the technology).

Going “downstream”, from the technology to the sale of goods, market signals enter the picture at opposite stages. First, market signals can act ex ante in the competition among different paradigms: if more paradigms are available, firms would select one or the other according to their expected profitability. But once a paradigm is affirmed, the direction of technological change would be already implied by its technological prescriptions. Second, market signals can act by selecting ex post those applications of the affirmed paradigm (i.e. the final products) that best fit the market requests. However, at that point their impact on the direction of technical change would be null, since such direction had already been decided by the prescriptions of the affirmed paradigm.

Going “upstream”, from the market environment to the technology, market signals act to inform the producers of the technology about variations in relative prices. However, the extent to which technology producers can shift from more expensive to cheaper inputs, or modify technology toward the use of cheaper complement goods is bound by technical constraints. Such constraints emerge because inputs are characterized by low substitutability due to the physical and chemical limits involved in the production process. Consequently, the upstream incentives given by market signals affect only the rate of use of certain inputs as well as the rate of development of a trajectory but not the direction of technical change, which is bound by the technical constraints of production.

Uncertainty

The trial and error procedures adopted by firms to improve along a technological trajectory  have taken Dosi to assess the issue of uncertainty. At a general level, trial and error procedures imply that firms might not be able to forecast completely the outcome of a choice they make; in fact, if they could foresee the error, they would presumably avoid it because it is costly. Such a fact is strongly at odds with any assumption of “perfect rationality” or “farsightedness” on the side of economic agents, which is a foundational element of the Neoclassical approach. Dosi has analyzed this issue by assessing the ways in which economic agents perceive and deal with choices that have an uncertain outcome. In analogy with Herbert A. Simon’s distinction about rationality, he has proposed the distinction between substantive uncertainty and procedural uncertainty. In his view, “the former is related to some lack of information about environmental events, while the latter concerns the competence gap in problem-solving”.Nonetheless, both of them generate “limitations on the computational and cognitive capabilities of the agents to pursue unambiguously their objectives”.Crucially, though, the fact that such types of uncertainties limit the computational rationality of agents leads them precisely to develop routines and decision rules that are the likely explanation of their heterogeneous behaviors. Moreover, even though such routines and decision rules are not optimally determined, they might well prove more “intelligent” than “optimal” decisions especially when applied to turbulent selection landscapes.

Heterogeneity

The fact that firms appear to be consistently heterogeneous has brought Dosi to criticize the Neoclassical prediction that firms in an industry converge toward some kind of “optimal” or “representative” characteristic. For such argument to be valid, the characteristics of firms would need to evolve in time toward a normal distribution, possibly showing some shrinking of the support. Notably, this theoretical implication poses an unresolved challenge to the arguments put forward by Milton Friedman in his essay The Methodology of Positive Economics. In such work Friedman asserted that maximizing behavior was a reasonable working approximation to describe the choices of economic agents: in fact, even if not all economic agents actually maximize (for example because some make mistakes) only the “fittest” ones will be selected by the market. Therefore, those agents that actually maximize would be the only “survivors” to market selection, and hence they would gather very closely around the single optimal behavior. In other words, the tails of the distribution will tend to disappear as market selects the best “genes”, which would turn out to be both “optimal” (in terms of fit to the market selection) and “representative” (since it would be the only surviving type). However, the empirical findings that constitute S.F.3 prove the exact opposite of Friedman’s prediction: very different “genes” survive to the market. As a consequence, a realistic representation of economic behavior should rather allow for firm-specificities, which would explain the heterogeneity found in the data: a point that was clearly made by Richard Nelson and Sidney Winter in their book An Evolutionary Theory of Economic Change

Important WORKS AND PUBLICATIONS

  • Dosi, G., Pavitt, K. and Soete L. The Economics of Technical Change and International Trade, Harvester Wheatsheaf, London (1990), pp.40-74.
  • Dosi, G., Freeman, C. and Fabiani, S., The Process of Economic Development: Introducing Some Stylized Facts and Theories on Technologies, Firms and Institutions, Industrial and Corporate Change, 3(1), (1994)
  • Dosi, G., Statistical regularities in the Evolution of Industries. A Guide through some Evidence and Challenges for the Theory, LEM Working Paper, 17, June, (2005).
  • Dosi, G., Technological paradigms and technological trajectories. A suggested interpretation of the determinants and directions of technical change, Research Policy, 11(3):147-162, (1982).
  • Dosi, G., Sources, Procedures, and Microeconomic Effects of Innovation, Journal of Economic Literature, 26(3):1120-1171, (1988).
  • Dosi, G. and Egidi, M., Substantive and procedural Uncertainty. An exploration of economic behavior in changing environments, Journal of Evolutionary Economics, 1(2):145-168, (1991).
  • Dosi, G., Statistical regularities in the Evolution of Industries. A Guide through some Evidence and Challenges for the Theory, LEM Working Paper, 17, June, (2005).
  • Dosi G., L. Soete, Technology and Employment in the ElectronicsIndustry, London, Francis Pinter, 1983
  • “Tecnologia, Struttura Industriale e Performance Economica Internazionale: Alcune Ipotesi Teoriche”, in F. Momigliano and G. Dosi,Tecnologia e Organizzazione Industriale, Bologna, Il Mulino, 1983
  • Dosi G., L. Soete, “Technology and Cost-Based Adjustments: Some Explorations on the Determinants of International Competitiveness”, Metroeconomica,

مطالب مرتبط


ارسال نظر

Go to TOP